The Carbon Forest

The Carbon Forest: A New Zealand Guide to Forest Carbon Sinks for Investors, Farmers, Foresters and ConservationistsA suburban section has long been the limit of my landowning ambition and I’m too old now to start thinking of anything more, but the prospect opened up by a newly published small book had me imagining I could well become interested if I were younger.  The book is The Carbon Forest: A New Zealand guide to forest carbon sinks for investors, farmers, foresters and conservationists (publisher’s site here). The four authors themselves appear motivated by climate change but the detailed advice they offer is far from tied to that concern. People looking to engage in a forestry venture for any reason, including reasonable financial return, will find the book very useful.

It is not written to engage the idly interested reader, though I can report it reasonably accessible for such. The aim is to provide practical information for people wondering about establishing a forest carbon sink on land they either already own or buy for the purpose. The authors describe forest sinks as currently by far the most effective form of carbon sequestration that humans can initiate. In New Zealand the government has identified forestry as the primary tool for meeting our Kyoto target for emissions reduction and has accordingly provided financial incentives for afforestation and reforestation. The book explains the four different government schemes available, the kinds of afforestation each of them is likely to suit and the kinds of carbon credits each can earn. It also acknowledges the voluntary schemes which may be preferred by those who wish to offset their carbon emissions voluntarily, and schemes which avoid trading in carbon credits such as those initiated by people who are purely interested in offsetting their own carbon emissions.

The procedures involved in carbon trading, both statutory and voluntary, and the currency of the carbon credit are made clear. The statutory schemes have been designed to help NZ reach its Kyoto target, though the book notes that this target falls short of what the science recommends, and that the most effective way of achieving the extra reductions is through the voluntary market. However the vast majority of forest sink owners now choose to trade through the statutory schemes which are generally easier and cheaper to deal with.

The analysis of different forest types and their sequestration rates is interesting. It shows that over a one-hundred-year period exotic trees, particularly Pinus radiata, absorb more carbon dioxide than native trees, but over longer periods native trees absorb more than exotics. The two options are not mutually exclusive for forest sink projects and the book indicates ways in which they can be usefully combined, sometimes to suit different soils and aspects within one block of land. The kind of management strategies that are proposed for a sink are an important ingredient in making decisions, and the book sets out some of the costs and returns for both low and high management approaches.

Finding the right kind of land for forest sinks at the right kind of price takes time and careful research. High value pastoral or agricultural land is patently not on the cards, but there is often marginal farmland on existing farms that may provide better return to the farmer if livestock are cleared out, the gate closed, scrub left to grow, and carbon credits claimed. Additional benefits such as erosion control may well accrue. Lifestyle block owners may find that the less intensive management required for growing trees than for raising livestock is appealing, along with the environmental benefits. Small pine plantations that turn out to be of poor quality or are difficult to access may be more profitable farmed as carbon than milled. Urbanites with environmental concerns may find suitable blocks of land for sale, and venture on a carbon sink which will return enough in carbon credits to at least cover costs and provide some additional financial benefit. The writers see good value in any sink which can sequester carbon at a cost of less than $20 per tonne of CO2, especially since the price of carbon is forecast to rise considerably. However they warn that it would be illusory to regard forest sinks as get rich quick schemes. Owners need to have regard for environmental as well as financial returns.

The structure of ownership may be influenced by the degree of financial return sought from the forestry. Multiple options, particularly companies, trusts and incorporated societies, are canvassed and broadly explained with pointers to further information and a warning of the importance of obtaining good legal and business advice. The place of statutory covenants or forestry right in obtaining long-term protection for a forest sink  is discussed, along with the finance, tax, and insurance matters that need to be taken into account in establishing the sink.

For one who had no idea of what might be involved in establishing carbon sinks under the regime which now obtains in New Zealand it was an eye-opener to see the wide ramifications explored in this practical guide book. It was also very encouraging to think that there will probably be many in the country who are starting to think about entering the various schemes available and that we have reason to hope for a big increase in tree planting and growing. A late chapter of case studies of existing forest sinks was reassuring after immersion in all the complexities explored earlier in the book. The case studies cover quite a range: a sink of 600 hectares on a 1600-hectare Marlborough farm; a 157-hectare exotic forest sink in Wairarapa established on a previous hilly sheep and cattle farm; the 642-hectare Queen Charlotte Wilderness Park; a 49-hectare block in Golden Bay of originally marginal farmland; and a 7.6-hectare Wairarapa lifestyle block managed by a Wellington owner.

One of the book’s four authors, Jonathan Kennett, has several years of experience managing reforestation projects and helped initiate the Golden Bay project listed above. Another, Simon Johnson, is a trustee of a forest carbon sink project and has worked as a resource management consultant. A third, Paul Kennett, an author, editor and web-designer, is described as living on a budget of less than 1 tonne CO2-e per annum. Finally, Tom Bennion, who has written some guest posts for Hot Topic in recent months, is a lawyer specialising in environmental and Maori law. It looks like a happy mix of environmental concern and relevant experience that has produced this informative book to help forest projects develop and flourish in the New Zealand landscape.

41 thoughts on “The Carbon Forest”

  1. This is great! Plant a forest and watch the money come in, while others do the real work.

    The ultimate socialists dream

    Have a nice Christmas [insult snipped. No more please. GR]

        1. Hi Bill,
          This was played from the Denialists’ Deck of Cards:
          8♠ “Duh!

          With “Duh!,” the denalist deliberately misunderstands, misinterprets, or plays dumb (in this case, switching Capitalism for Socialism).

          This is also a variant of the Straw man argument (carbon sequestration is independent of economic philosophy). When employed as the opening comment to a post, it is known as a “piñata” argument (one hoping to attract wild swings at a comically poorly-formed construct).

          rotflmao. Still better to DNFTT.

          Cheers, and Merry Christmas!

    1. ….while others do the real work…. such as shoveling more coals into the firebox, adding speed to the proverbial freight train before it hits the proverbial brick wall……

  2. It will be good to see marginal land that was cleared for pastoral use returned to forests. There will be ‘downstream’ benefits besides carbon sequestration – a reduction in erosion and increased habitat for native birds, for instance.

    1. And don’t forget that “proper” full-scale re-forestation (or initiating it as at Ascension Island) has massive impacts of the hydrology of a region. More rainfall – and properly absorbed into soil rather than running off taking the topsoil with it – has got to be a boon.

  3. Well, you took the bait. Of course, I don’t regard these “carbon forests” (what other kind are there?) as a feature of socialism. Quite the opposite in fact.

    Every dollar paid to one of these “investors” is a dollar taken out of the productive economy.A dollar that could be spent on, for example, healthcare or education.

    While we pay “entrepreneurs” to grow weeds (radiata pine) that does not support much in the way of biodiversity, we still require someone to actually burn the coal or oil to pay for it in the first place. That is how the ETS works.

    1. Happy Xmas?

      It’s the 27th, and your comment might upset people of non-religious or non-Christian faiths.

      And please don’t say Happy Holidays. Holiday is derived from Holy Day.
      And please don’t say happy, it might upset unhappy people.

      And please don’t say day-off, it might upset those who have to work.

      Thanks

      (that will probably upset people too)

  4. Hey John: That is a bit crass. Indeed, very crass

    Actually I am an atheist. But I’m not so rude that I wouldn’t want to wish “Merry Xmas” to you and everyone else at this time of year. So Merry Xmas to you

    As far as those who have to work, all I have to say is “let those who live In glass houses cast the last stones” .

    And yEs, I am still working in case that matters to you.

  5. And just in case you didn’t notice I never said “happy holidays”‘ “happy” or even “day off” although I am sure that Artful Dodger will have some cards to deliver in that regard. All would seem to hit the mark!

    Once again, a very Merry Xmas to you!

    1. Prof Hunter,
      You are correct that you did not say “Happy Holidays”.
      My statement was a form of future imperative, such as “don’t walk on the grass”.

      It was intended as a form of parody, of political correctness, a construct of cultural Marxism, that one finds amusing as the proponents of such find my calling a 25 year old a “kid” offensive.

      Yet, the same people, yourself included, can refer to me as a “troll” for expressing what I consider to be a valid criticism of so-called carbon farming

      “Denier”, “crank” “troll”, all words we have come to expect from the “liberal” intellectual elite from which you presumably classify yourself under.

        1. what a troll considers to be valid is not a test of validity that the rest of us generally bother with.

          Replace “troll” with “Jew”, “Black” or your favorite minority group, and see how you sound to me matey.

          1. Being a troll is about how you behave not a genetic property of an individual. You are labelled a troll because you consistently behave like one. You claim to want discussion and debate but really never engage beyond the standard troll toolkit.
            I’m sorry if you think you’re some kind of persecuted minority but I’m not going to waste my energy having earnest debates with someone who is plainly only interested in disrupting useful dialogue about climate change…

      1. “all words we have come to expect ”
        if you behave like a troll – and you do – then you should, of course, expect to be labeled as such. but feel free to whinge about it, as I’m sure there are a host of trolls willing to sympathise…

        1. It also never occurred to you that transferring wealth from the general public to private forestry owners might actually be construed as unfair by some. Even, perhaps, a scam.

          You are so busy defending your turf against “the troll” that you cannot under any circumstances actually admit that I might have a point, that I am defending the rights of the punter and you are defending rich corporates.

          1. “It also never occurred to you that transferring wealth from the general public to private forestry owners might actually be construed as unfair by some. Even, perhaps, a scam.”

            In our Capitalist economy John – that’s how it works.
            Some like it. Most don’t even know that is what it is all about, Others (and maybe your one – or coming to that realisation) – see it for what it is – a big scam to line the pockets of the wealthy.

            Up until now and, at the present time, fossil fuel companies (coal gas and oil) have been, and are, subsidized heavily by the general public and future generations as we and our descendants pick up the tab for pollution of the environment and the atmosphere. These externalities (as the economists call them) are not paid for by Mobil, Exxon, Shell, BP, et al but by you and me and those in the future.

            So with that in mind – what are you going to do about it?

            1. Explain to me how fossil fuel companies are subsidised by the general public.

              Surely, if this is the case, then we just remove the subsidies and the wind and solar power all becomes so compelling?

              I have never ever heard this argument put forward.

            2. “I have never ever heard this argument put forward.”

              Maybe you have cloth ears John. But yes your right! Wind Solar and other alternative Energies are, compared to FF, way more cost effective when the externalised costs of FF are taken into account.

              For an overview of what externalised costs, in relation to FF is all about there is this:
              http://www.ucsusa.org/clean_energy/technology_and_impacts/impacts/the-hidden-cost-of-fossil.html
              Its not just adding CO2 to the atmosphere.

            3. you mean the costs of the gulf war are an externality of fossil fuel reliance? why, wouldn’t that make them about the most ridiculously expensive source of energy ever?

            4. “Surely, if this is the case, then we just remove the subsidies and the wind and solar power all becomes so compelling?”

              surely… and yet you see to be pretty vehemently against any kind of carbon tax or other measure to make those corporations (whom you are supposedly defending us punters against) pay for the damage their products are doing to global ecosystems…

            5. Explain how FF is subsidised by the general public?

              Heavens. There are direct subsidies and grants for both exploration and mining itself – who pays for the rail lines that coal mining needs to get to port? Who pays for the ports? Who pays the rates and other charges to local governments when those local governments have granted exemptions and concessions to refineries or cement or aluminium manufacturers?

              And that’s all on top of direct subsidies and exemptions of various kinds that FF companies get for various reasons all around the world.

              You really need to get out more or stay in and read lots of information..

            6. “you mean the costs of the gulf war are an externality of fossil fuel reliance? why, wouldn’t that make them about the most ridiculously expensive source of energy ever?”

              Many argue that the primary reason for the 1st and 2nd Gulf Wars were substantially just that! The need to secure the continued supply to the US of Middle Eastern Oil with the “unstable” Iraq controlled by Hussain. That may not have been the publically stated reason for the unilateral invasion resulting in the continued occupation. But there is no doubt it was a contributing factor. And yes! It would make Oil the most expensive energy source there is! But this is not the only occasion that wars have been waged over securing a supply of Oil. You may also note that it was the insecurity of supply from the Middle East to Japan that was a contributing factor for the entry of Japan into WW2, as it fought to secure a sea route via the Straits of Singapore and the China sea and the pre-emptive strike on Pearl Harbour.

            7. Perhaps one of the most harrowing of stories concerning securing the supply of oil is that of the convoy to Malta in WW2 when it was vital to the defence of the Island that at least one Oil tanker arrived.
              An externalised cost in ships and lives on both sides.

            8. nommopilot – I did understand your ironic tone.
              I do think though that the point does need to be made and made forcefully that the externalised costs of FF are not insubstantial nor inconsequential to human life.

Leave a Reply